Albion Monitor /Commentary

The Anti-Trust Juggernaut Crushes the Little Guy

by Charles E. Mueller

(AR) The number of antitrust cases filed in the U.S. courts has dwindled by over 75 percent in the last couple of decades -- from some 1700 in 1977 to about 400 today when anticompetitive mergers and market consolidation has progressed to a degree that might have been unthinkable just 20 years ago.

The Justice Department's Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commision were each bringing about 100 cases per year back then; now, they pursue a couple of dozen. Can we safely assume that corporate America has suddenly cleaned up its act and stopped engaging in anticompetitive practices? Not likely.

Let the biggest buy up or crush the small and get it over with as quickly as possible
Given the permissive Reagan/Bush antitrust policies of the '80s, and now the Clinton administration's open encouragement of industry "consolidation," more antitrust violations are occurring today than in any period since the turn of the last century.

So what has happened? The cases aren't being filed for a very good reason: the injured plaintiffs (and their lawyers) know they simply can't win.

Why can't a business enterprise that's been destroyed by an antitrust violation win its case in 1997? Put bluntly, the crushed entrepreneur can't win because the corporate bully is shielded by a phalanx of recent Supreme Court decisions. No matter what facts he is able to prove, they won't be enough to withstand the "economic" tests or standards laid down in these opinions.

Predatory (below-cost) pricing to kill a competitor? Perfectly legal, says the Court. A new merger creates a duopoly (a choice of only two suppliers) in a major industry? No problem, says the Court; prices won't rise. Discriminatory prices that give retail giants (e.g., Wal-Mart) the ability to sell for less than their smaller competitors PAY their common supplier? Competition, says the Court, will not be hurt. Restrictive contracts with suppliers and customers that bar competitors and potential entrants from the most lucrative markets? Way to go, says the Court; the fewer the firms, the more "efficient" U.S. industry will be.

With the acceptance of that latter principle -- that Soviet-style "gigantomania" is the key to economic "efficiency" -- all the business practices of our 19th Century robber barons are automatically legalized (with the possible exception of the elder Rockefeller's dynamiting of a competing oil refiner off a bluff in Buffalo).

If the widget industry has 20 competing firms, and our 1,000 federal judges "know" that eliminating all but one or two of them will make costs (and thus consumer prices) fall, why be squeamish about the means used to get to that economically-optimal goal? Let the biggest buy up or crush the small and get it over with as quickly as possible.

The U.S. Supreme Court has, with no authorization from Congress, changed the country's basic economic policy
The U.S. Supreme Court, in other words, no longer believes that competition makes sense. The country's antitrust laws -- the Sherman Act of 1890; the Federal Trade Commisson Act of 1914; and the Clayton Act of 1914, as amended by the Price Discrimination Act of 1936 and the Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Act of 1950 -- are all still on the books exactly as Congress wrote them. But the books are gathering dust.

Instead, our highest Court, in its role as the protector of "property" in America, now simply refuses to permit their enforcement. Its nine justices have made themselves the nation's "economists," adopting the so-called Chicago school of economic theory that favors the "consolidation" of U.S. industry -- and the enhanced "stockholder value" that comes with predatory and monopolistic pricing.

One of the ironies that emerged as I compiled a list of Supreme Court decisions that have killed U.S. antitrust enforcement, is that some of the worst offenders have been the most "liberal" of the individual justices, e.g., Brennan and Marshall. They apparently had no difficulty at all in swallowing the theory -- promoted at the University of Chicago school of economics -- that the biggest corporation is the most efficient.

The Supreme Court cases that are now giving the country a rerun of of The Octopus are embossed in gold leaf and carried in the briefcase of every corporate lawyer in America who has a Bill Gates for a boss, and together they form a legal blueprint for monopolizing an American industry. They are:

  • Continental TV v. GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. 36 (1977)
  • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977)
  • Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752 (1984)
  • Jefferson Parish Hospital v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984)
  • Matsushita Electric v. Zenith Radio, 475 U.S. 574 (1986)
  • Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, 479 U.S. 104 (1986)
  • Business Electronics v. Sharp Electronics, 485 U.S. 717 (1988)
  • Atlantic Richfield v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990)
  • Brooke (Liggett) v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco (June 21, 1993)
  • Through this group of decisions, the U.S. Supreme Court has, with no authorization from Congress, changed the country's basic economic policy -- which prior to 1975 had favored unconcentrated industries and competitive prices -- and are now reshaping the American economy into a group of two-firm and even one-firm industries -- the kind that from antiquity to the present have led only to bloat, inflated prices, vast disparities of income and wealth and, in the words of Adam Smith, the unjust "oppression of the poor."

    Charles E. Mueller is Editor of the Florida-based Antitrust Law & Economics Review


    Comments? Send a letter to the editor.

    Albion Monitor February 4, 1997 (http://www.monitor.net/monitor)

    All Rights Reserved.

    Contact rights@monitor.net for permission to reproduce.

    Front Page